Sunday, November 24, 2019

Yahoo Case Analysis Example

Yahoo Case Analysis Example Yahoo Case Analysis – Case Study Example Yahoo case analysis Yahoo!’s Strategy and its Transition under the Different CEO’s Yahoo!’s original strategy was to capitalize on advertisement revenues for its income and profitability. This implied attraction and retention of advertisers through maintaining an audience base that the advertisers would target. The strategy experienced multiple transitions under different CEO’s but with the aims of sustaining profitability and value to investors. Semel replaced Koogle as the company’s chief executive and changed the strategy to target diversified sources of revenues that included job search services and music services. Acquisition of firms that offered this services became part of the strategy that also included development of the company’s own search engine. With the appointment of Bartz, Yahoo!’s strategy shifted to managerial efficiency and content quality in which reshuffles and employee turnover occurred. Transition in strategy al so occurred under Mayer with focus on employees’ morale, quality content, and innovation. These changes in strategy have however focused on ensuring profitability and satisfaction of the company’s investors. Marissa’s Initiatives for Configuring Yahoo, Remaining Challenges and Analysis of Success PossibilityMarissa Mayer has initiated diversified changes in her bid to configure Yahoo! She has offered employees new phones and free services at the cafeteria in an attempt to boost employees’ morale. She has also changed Yahoo!’s web page and brought in new talent for quality improvements. She has also changed the organization’s human resource tradition of working from home and required all employees to work from the company’s offices. Mayer has succeeded in reviving the company and the remaining challenges are need for sustainability and need for improvements. Based on her experience with a competing firm and the success that she has mad e, since previous executives failed to attain this, she is likely to succeed in ensuring sustainability and improvement in the firm’s revenue, investors’ satisfaction, and customers’ base.

Thursday, November 21, 2019

Archaeology Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 500 words

Archaeology - Essay Example In â€Å"Fishing from past to present: continuity and resilience of red abalone fisheries on the Channel Islands, California†, Braje et al. develop an 8000-year time-line employing archaeological data from the Holocene and historical data from the last century and a half â€Å"with the objective of integrating deep time into modern resource management.† (906) In 1997 emergency closure by the California Fish and Game Commission was instituted on the red abalone fishery in response to what was viewed as a catastrophic decline in the red abalone population. However, according to Braje et al., the archaeological record indicates that â€Å"anthropologic trophic cascades began some 8000-7500 years ago along the Santa Barbara Coast.† (917) In other words, the number of various prey and predator species has oscillated significantly over the last eight millennium along the Santa Barbara Coast. This optimistically indicates that the current decline in the red abalone popu lations is not necessarily permanent.

Wednesday, November 20, 2019

Quiz Assignment Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 750 words - 4

Quiz - Assignment Example Even though the concept of neoclassical economics has gained fame through the implementation by various economists, there are critics on the principle. The economists who were majorly involved in the neoclassical concept in economics are George Stigler, John Hicks, William Stanley, John Bates Clark, and Carl Menger (Frostater, 23). Neoclassical approach is based on several features that are common in various schools of economic thought. A prominent economist called Roy Weintraub argued that the neoclassical economic concept if based on three assumptions that; consumers concentrate on utility maximization while firms concentrate on profit maximization, people are always operating independently due to the fact of relying on the relevant information and there is also a great perception in the aspect of rationale preferences in the individuals. The idea of neoclassical criticism brings the element of imperfect completion in the market. This happens in various ways such as; large business organizations may come together with a goal of neoclassical profit maximization but if there is a rejection in social issues, there is a problem, making the neoclassical equilibrium theory companionable with the economic situation delays thus creating chances for poor performance. There are complex mathematical concepts that are challenging to relate with the current economic situations in the markets. This section concentrates on some three strategic programs that are required in order to meet the long-term economic policies and goals of Stockholm such as becoming a state that is carbon neutral, clean technology and facilitating the economic opportunities from green innovation technology (Frostater, 71). The three sectors are improving urban transport and accessibility, production of energy resources that are free from carbon and creativity or innovation in the business premises. Maintenance of

Monday, November 18, 2019

Homeland Security Organization Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 250 words

Homeland Security Organization - Essay Example Newspapers have often reported that handling the effects of attacks by weapons of destruction demands the service of military, welfare organizations and local agencies. At present the nation faces severe attacks that may be so devastating, unexpected and complex. Existing system of original homeland security in USA has certain limitations. Emergency military operations, rehabilitation and medicinal aids are not possible in current system of original home security organization. Circumstances require coordinated or more integrated forms of homeland security organization in the United States. These types of integrated homeland security organization promote effective prevention methods, proper response, and rehabilitation programs to terrorist attacks and other natural calamities. Terrorist attacks and various natural calamities such as storm, earthquake and epidemic diseases affect a large area and prevention methods and rehabilitation activities should conduct in different places in a same time. Laegreid & Serigstad (2004) clearly remark that â€Å"changes, implementation and Improvement is reactive in character, which, in turn, causes considerable diffusion of responsibility between ministries, agencies and other public and private bodies† (p. 8). Collective responsibility of various agencies is essential for the successive implementation of homeland security organization and proper coordination should be ensured for the smooth functioning of variou s agencies. Coordinated homeland security program ensure the effective organization of the government in to the activities of various agencies. Laegreid, P & Serigstad, S. (November 2004). Organizing for Homeland Security: The Case of Norway. Stein Rokkan Centre for Social Studies. Retrieved 17 Jul. 10, from:

Friday, November 15, 2019

Management of a Care Facility

Management of a Care Facility Introduction Managers are tasked to create their organisation’s vision in such a way that it will aide in assuring future stability. This academic paper will discuss how an organisation’s vision is created, communicated and implemented and how this vision will pave the way for conceptualizing its strategic direction in a chosen residential home. The residential home care that was discussed in this paper is a home care that provides older adult services to about 60-70 residents with various geriatric needs. The residential home care is divided into units depending on the needs assessments made on each resident during their admission. There are about four nearby residential home cares providing the same services. The home care is the newest of the four and is gradually gaining recognition within the serviceable area. In its everyday operations, bulk of the employees consists of nurses and health care aides. Major problems faced by the organisation are the shortage of nursing staff along with the need to expand the business due to increase influx of clients being admitted. The vision and its stakeholders An organisational vision is a statement of what the organisation wants to do and hopes to become in the future (Nagelkerk, 2005). In creating a vision, it must first be congruent with mission and philosophy of the organisation and anchored on shared values and beliefs (Polifko-Harris, 2005). At the same time, the vision must be dynamic and motivational to its stakeholders because the vision is said to be meaningful only to those who are involved in its creation (Roussel, 2011; Thamm, 2011; Allen, 2007) A stakeholder is a person or a group that takes strong interest on organisation (Kelly and Tazbir, 2013). In health care industries such as the residential home care, the stakeholders include the patients or clients, nurses, medical practitioners, insurers, administrators, and accrediting bodies (Kelly and Tazbir, 2013). In vision planning, consideration of the stakeholders and fostering a good relationship with them are very crucial as their involvement and engagement in the organisation can bring the vision into reality (Kelly and Tazbir, 2013; Malloch and Porter-O’Grady, 2010). They must be adequately represented as they are expected to support management initiatives and perform certain roles for fulfilling organisational success (Gantz, 2010; Harris et al, 2010). As Sare and Ogilvie (2010) say, nursing is a people-centered profession and thrives in involvement. The more we get to involve people to share in the organisational vision, there is higher likelihood that the visi on will be put to reality. Oftentimes, it is heard that only those in the middle and upper management make decisions and policies for the organisation. However, it is not only them who must be involved in creating the vision. In the chosen health care setting, the stakeholders include the elderly residents and their families, the nursing personnel and other employees, unit managers and supervisors and the board of directors. Feedbacks and perceptions of service users are crucial in service improvements. Thus, satisfaction of the elderly residents and their families must be solicited from them. Moreover, the people working for the company especially the nursing staff who provide direct nursing care must be considered. Nurse leaders need to make the employees committed to the organisation and gain ownership of its goals and objectives so that the vision can be brought to reality (McIntyre and McDonald, 2013). Nurses who are motivated and satisfied in their work are more likely to perform better that contribute t o better patient outcomes (Potter et al, 2014). As mentioned, the home care is now facing a shortage of nursing staff which can affect their level of dedication and work quality (McGilton et al, 2013; Peng et al, 2013). This should be one of the things that must be considered if the management would want to make the nursing staff form a sense of ownership of the vision. Factors that may impact the organisational vision Aside from the stakeholders, there are influential factors that must be paid attention to if the organisation is to create a feasible vision. Intrinsic and extrinsic factors can be assessed using SWOT analysis (Kelly and Tazbir, 2013). These factors that need consideration include the areas of operation, finances, competition, changing needs of clients, technological advances, changing political climate, market conditions, economy, competition, current trends and issues in healthcare (Nagelkerk, 2005). Organisational vision and strategic decision In consideration of the characteristics of the residential home care, its stakeholders and other environmental factors, the created vision is written below: â€Å"Our vision is to be the foremost residential home care for older adults in the community that promotes independence and higher quality of life through excellent and safe nursing care. The next step would be to create the strategic direction for the organisation. In the strategic management process, the strategic direction is the long term goals and objectives of the organisation that outlines the purposes of the organisation and its operational scope (Enz, 2009). It must be anchored on the organisation’s mission and vision statements (Enz, 2009). In consideration of the strategic direction, the organisational competencies will be assessed together with surrounding environmental factors (Wilson, 2005). In developing the strategic direction, answers to the following questions will be sought with the help of the management and key stakeholders: 1) What are the expertise of the home care?; 2) What kind of home care will it be in three or five years?; 3) What type of population will we be serving?; 4) What additional functions or services are we going to provide given the evolving market?; 5) What are the technology requirements given the evolving market?; and 6 ) What changes are taking place in the internal and external market that will affect the home care? (Paley, 1999). Communicating the vision One of the qualities of a highly effective leader is the ability to make the people involved in the organisation understand and remain committed to the vision (Gill, 2011). Continuous and sustainable communication of the vision enables members to be clearly informed of the current status of the organisation and its future directions (Gill, 2011). When properly communicated, shared vision prospers and stakeholders will most likely understand their roles and responsibilities in realising the vision inspite of uncertainties and problems along the way (Papp, 2001). The created vision will be communicated by: 1) finding key persons who will motivate others to listen and be engaged in the vision; 2) setting-up a formal communication team who will disseminate the new vision through advertisements and staff education; 3) including the vision in marketing ads of the home care; 4) place posters containing the vision in strategic locations within the organisation; 5) spark conversations among p eople around about the new vision; 6) create activities such as contests that are themed based on the vision; 7) get other’s feedback and perception of the new vision through personal interviews and group discussions; and 8) use social media and other information-dissemination technology that will keep others informed and reminded of the vision (Center for Creative Leadership, Cartwright and Baldwin, 2011). Right leadership for vision sharing For the organisation to see the fulfillment of its vision, everyone with vested interest in it must work collectively through appropriate leadership and management behaviours. Making everybody feel that they own and share a common vision is a major focus of transformational leadership. According to Bass and Riggio (2006), leaders must appeal to the followers’ sense of self-worth to ensure their commitment and involvement in the entire efforts and activities of the organisation. Transformational leaders motivate their followers to always put their best in what they do, empower them by making them involved in crucial organisational activities, and allow them to expand their potentials and abilities (Bass and Riggio, 2006). Followers are able also to develop a strong sense of identification with the organisation that moves them to working and thinking not just to suffice their self-interests (Hutchinson and Jackson, 2012).In nursing, transformational leadership has been seen as a model of leadership that is enabling, empowering and suitable for nurses to remain committed to excellent and safe care practises (Lievens and Vlerick, 2014; Ross et al, 2014; Schwartz et al, 2011). To embed the vision to the followers, the leaders must employ the four components of transformational leadership. These are idealised influence, inspirational motivation, intellectual stimulation and individual consideration (Doody and Doody, 2012; Schwartz et al, 2011). In idealised influence, the leader must be seen by the followers as a role model (Doody and Doody, 2012). The manager of the home care must set an example by ensuring that all personal actions are in accordance with the vision. They must be the frontline communicator of the vision to the staff and be the first person to act when everyone is having difficulty fulfilling the vision (Doody and Doody, 2012). Inspirational motivation must also be applied by encouraging followers to always work to achieve organisational goals and objectives while at the same time achieving their own goals (Bally, 2007). Allowing members to participate in decision and policy-making exemplifies intellectual stimulation (Schwartz et al, 2011) . For example, the nursing staff can be involved in projects and programmes that will be launched to achieve the vision and strategic direction of the home care. Lastly, leaders in the home care must be open to the individual needs of the followers by supporting them in their actions, giving them recognition for their efforts and allowing them to achieve professional growth (Schwartz et al, 2011). Rewards and incentives can be given to those staff who exceptionally performed to achieve the goals set by the home care. They may also be given opportunities for further trainings and in-service education to make them more competent. In turn, these activities can bring about better services and improved patient outcomes. Organisational objectives Organisational objectives are the prescribed actions that will be used to achieve and evaluate organisational goals (Kelly, 2011). Based on the vision, the following are the organisational objectives: Our residential home care aims to: Deliver client-centered and holistic care to our residents Create a therapeutic environment for our clients Provide compassionate, ethical, safe, caring and dependable nursing services Commit ourselves to quality improvement and safety standards Increase the services we provide based on our clients’ changing needs Put the organisation and clients’ needs first before our own interests Respect, value and empower people within the organisation Support individual growth and opportunities Increase stakeholders’ satisfaction Move for organisational stability and viability Strategic planning process Strategic planning is the process of setting the future direction of the organisation through alignment of its mission and vision with its actions to achieve the desired outcomes (Feldman and Alexander, 2012). The strategic planning process that will be done follows Odiorne’s recommendations (as cited in Swansburg, 1996): Gap analysis. This involves identification of the problems of the organisation in order to determine what the organisation wants to do about it in the future. Examining extrinsic factors. Assess outside influences that contribute to the problems identified. Enumerate the critical issues. From a pool of problems identified, select the most pressing issues and those which more likely create a high-impact on the organisation. Ranking the important. Plan according to the most important issues for the organisation. Decide. Decide on the issues by involving all key stakeholders. Time and resource planning. Construct a time frame as to when the objectives should be met. This will also include identifying who will be responsible and the resources that will be needed. Summary and Conclusion Managing an organisation is never an easy task. It gets more difficult as the organisation becomes more complex and the needs of stakeholders continue to rise. Nurse managers and leaders must be able to consider all factors inside and outside of the organisation and every individual who has an interest to it. Leaders and managers must craft a well-defined and shared vision to make everyone involved in the organisation to remain committed and motivated towards fulfilling it. Such work will entail the need to adopt transformational leadership through idealised influence, inspirational motivation, intellectual stimulation and individual consideration. With the new vision, it is likewise necessary to craft the strategic direction and objectives of the organisation. In doing so, leader-managers must be able to align these to the vision, mission, philosophy, and values of the organisation. When all of these are in place, the organisation can now move to making a strategic plan for the entire organisation.

Wednesday, November 13, 2019

Brown versus Board of Education Essay -- Race Segregation

Imagine that your walk to school lasts longer that sixty minutes even though a school is five minutes away. When you finally get there, you enter a shack with makeshift tables and a dirt floor. You do not get paper or writing utensils and you surely do not get good books. Your teacher, who did not even finish her education, hands you a book that another school determined outdated and tossed away. But on one glorious day, May 17, 1954, a promise of change is made. The Supreme Court gave you the right to attend that school at the end of your block, a previously designated white school (Rodgers 1). The next day you and your parents wear nice clothes and walk down the street to the school to enroll for the following school year. You get there and stand proud of yourself and of your new school as you move towards the Dean’s office. You are confronted with terrifying looks of disgust from your white counterparts as they deny you admission based on the color of your skin. Un fortunately, for many African Americans, this was a reality in the years following the Brown versus Board of Education decision (Stephan 19). Although we have made considerable progress since then, our job is far from finished. When examining statistics on testing scores, the quality of schools with African Americans making the majority, on housing segregation and white flight, it quickly becomes apparent that whites and blacks have different numbers. This is due primarily to the ongoing perspective that black people are inferior to them dating back to the pre-emancipation period. Even at the fiftieth anniversary of the infamous Brown versus Board of Education decision, discrepancies between the races remain prevalent. Oliver L. Brown painstakingly wat... ...earch/reseg04/brown50.pdf>. Orfield, Gary, Daniel Iosen, Johanna Wald, and Christopher B. Swanson. â€Å"Losing our Future: How Minority Youths are being Left Behind by the Graduation Rate Crisis.† The Civil Rights Project. 25 Feb. 2004 . Rogers, Frederick A. The Black High School and Its Community. Massachusetts: Lexington Books, 1975. Stephan, Walter G., and Joe R. Feagin, eds. School Desegregation: Past, Present, and Future. New York: Plenum Press, 1980. Toppo, Greg. â€Å"Integrated Schools Still a Dream 50 Years Later.† USA Today 28 Apr. 2004. United States. Bureau of the Census. Historical Income Tables. Washington: GPO, 2001. Yamasaki, Mitch. â€Å"Using Rock ‘N’ Roll to Teach the History of Post-World War II America.† The History Teacher 29.2 (1996): 179-193.

Sunday, November 10, 2019

A Bergerian Reading and Chris “Ludacris” Bridges

The whole of our existence is shaped by our experiences – the various situations that we find ourselves in. Parts of our experiences are influenced by what we see, and what we see takes us to new levels of experiences that allow us to situate ourselves in thoughts or visions represented by what we virtually perceive.Interpretations of visual texts, such as works of art, therefore are based on our perceptions and points of view, consequently leading to subjectivity despite the conventional meanings embedded within these works of art by the artist.Under these pretexts, various works of art, borne out of the social events, situations, or landscapes in the past, become subjects of mystification. Such are the views or perspectives of John Berger on art, particularly on Franz Hals’ portraits, the â€Å"Regents of the Old Men’s Alms House† and the â€Å"Regentesses of the Old Men’s House† (1580-1666) – that the social construct from which the se works were created are mystified because of its incongruity to modern times.Berger, a seasoned art critique, presented a complex yet analytical perspective on the works of Hals, focusing on their being representative of history and how they are inevitably mystified not only by our perspectives as inhabitants of the modern day world but also Hals’, in his own words, oversimplification of what the portraits truly imply.Moreover, because of Berger’s analysis and personal critiques on the work of Hals, we as viewers of the visual text, begin to understand that the portraits are not merely images that represent superficial artistic and social elements such as unity and harmony, the ideas formed from observing facial expressions, gestures, and such.Furthermore, Hals’ works of art are snapshots of the social and economic situations that the artist, the regents and the regentesses found themselves in.The portraits seem to capture the kind of relationship that exists between the artist and the subjects of art, expressing something more – a drama that represents a historical landscape that is shared by Hals and his subjects within a social environment that was illuminated and solidified by large gaps among social groups or classes – brought to life by Hals’ artistry and ingà ©nue in translating emotions and perspectives to visual arts.The analytical perspectives of Berger as explored in his interpretations of Hals’ portraits shall be utilized to describe the messages or arguments evident in a portrait taken of the actor/rapper Chris â€Å"Ludacris† Bridges. In order to do so, it is highly significant to go over Berger’s perceptions or points of view on viewing art, particularly of Hals’ portraits, by creating a framework from which the visual analysis of the Ludacris’ portrait shall be based on.According to Berger, the act of viewing pieces of art may be done in various ways depending on: a ) one’s perspective, b) the artists’ perspective, c) other people’s perspectives, d) the social, economic, or political situations within which the piece of art was conceptualized, and e) the present social, economic, or political situations completing a shared link between the past and the present.Moreover, Berger stressed that it is equally important that in order to understand the genuine sense or value of pieces of art, that viewers look or interpret them beyond their personal perspectives and the pictorial nature of the portrait.Viewing art should not adhere to convention of perspectives that was existent during the Renaissance because it limits the span of pieces of art to convey deeper and comprehensive meanings. The convention of perspectives isolates what the viewer might all-inclusively learn cognitively, emotionally or psychologically, socially, spiritually and such.Therefore, reading or interpreting visual texts should be a combination of one’ s perspectives as they relate to the artists’ and other people’s perspectives, and the connections between the social, economic, and political situations from past to present. Human beings should also be aware that they are represented by and connected to art, as art is also able to view the viewer because of shared visual perspectives.The key to analyzing Ludacris’ portrait is to view it radically, if we are to align ourselves with Berger’s ideologies and perspectives. Ludacris’ portrait, being an image intended to represent remarkable style to signify celebrity-like success, borders on deception and absurdity.The explicit message that the artist photographer Robert Maxwell intended to express was associated with the vision of Moà «t & Chandon; and that is, how adapting elegant, stylish, and distinctive fashion may be translated to remarkableness and success in the limelight that are consequently significant causes for celebration This argument i s solidified by the nature of the camera – a narrow and limited perspective of things and situations – utilized by Maxwell in order to represent a specific idea or though restricted by the visualizations or representations of Moà «t & Chandon, an well-known international producer of champagne that embodies conceptions of â€Å"splendour, pleasure, and prestige.† (Moà «t & Chandon)

Friday, November 8, 2019

The Productivity of Information Technology Essay Example

The Productivity of Information Technology Essay Example The Productivity of Information Technology Essay The Productivity of Information Technology Essay THE PRODUCTIVITY OF INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY: Review and Assessment Erik Brynjolfsson CCS TR #125 December, 1991 This research was sponsored by the MIT Center for Coordination Science, the MIT International Financial Services Research Center, and the Sloan Foundation. Special thanks are due Michael Dertouzos and Tom Malone for encouraging me to pursue this topic as part of a study group at the MIT Laboratory for Computer Science. I would like to thank Ernie Berndt, Geoffrey Brooke, and Chris Kemerer for valuable comments and Marshall Van Alstyne and Peter Perales for excellent research assistance. Only I am responsible for any remaining deficiencies The Productivity of Information Technology: Review and Assessment Erik Brynjolfsson Abstract Productivity is the bottom line for any investment. The quandary of information technology (IT) is that, despite astonishing improvements in the underlying capabilities of the computer, its productivity has proven almost impossible to assess. There is an increasing perception that IT has not lived up to its promise, fueled in part by the fact that the existing empirical literature on IT productivity generally has not identified significant productivity improvements. However, a careful review, whether at the level of the economy as a whole, among information workers, or in specific manufacturing and service industries, indicates that the evidence must still be considered inconclusive. It is premature to surmise that computers have been a paradoxically unwise investment. A puzzle remains in the inability of both academics and managers to document unambiguously the performance effects of IT. Four possible explanations are reviewed in turn: mismeasurement, lags, redistribution and mismanagement. The paper concludes with recommendations for investigating each of these explanations using traditional methodologies, while also proposing alternative, broader metrics of welfare that ultimately may be required to assess, and enhance, the benefits of IT. Keywords: Productivity, Computers, Performance measurement, Economic value, Investment justification. CONTENTS The Productivity Paradox A Clash of Expectations and Statistics . 1 Dimensions of the Paradox .. Economy-wide Productivity and Information Worker Productivity . . 7.. The Productivity of Information Technology Capital in Manufacturing 11 The Productivity of Information Technology Capital in Services . 15 Leading Explanations for the Paradox .. 19 Measurement Errors 20 Lags . 5 Redistribution .. 28 Mismanagement . . 229. 9. Con clusio. n.. 32 Summary . . . 32 Where Do We Go From Here? . 34 Tables and Graphs . .. 40 Bibliography . 4477. Information Technology and Productivity The Productivity Paradox A Clash of Expecta tions and Statistics The relationship between information technology (IT) and productivity is widely discussed but little understood. On one hand, delivered computing-power in the US economy has increased by more than two orders of magnitude in the past two decades (figure 1). On the other hand, roductivity, especially in the service sector, seems to have stagnated (figure 2). Given the enormous promise of IT to usher in the biggest technological revolution men have known (Snow, 1966), disillusionment and even frustration with the technology is increasingly evident in statements like No, computers do not boost productivity, at least not most of the time (Economist, 1990) and headlines like Computer Data Overload Limits Productivity Gains (Zachary, 1991) and Computers Arent Pulling Their Weight (Berndt Morrison, 1991a). The increased interest in the productivity paradox, as it has become known, has engendered a significant amount of research, but, thus far, this has only deepened the mystery. The results are aptly characterized by Robert Solows quip that we see computers everywhere except in the productivity statistics, and Bakos and Kemerers (1991) more recent summation that These studies have fueled a controversial debate, primarily because they have failed to document substantial productivity improvements attributable to information technology investments. Although similar conclusions are repeated by an alarming number of researchers in this area, we must be careful not to overinterpret these findings; a shortfall of evidence is not necessarily evidence of a shortfall. Nonetheless, given the increasing significance of IT in the budgets of most businesses and in the nation as a whole, continued investment cannot be justified by blind faith alone. Draft: 1/29/92 page 1 Information Technology and Pr oductivity This paper seeks to contribute to the research effort by summarizing what we know and dont know, by distinguishing the central issues from diversions, and by clarifying the questions that can be profitably explored in future research. After reviewing and assessing the research to date, it appears that the shortfall of IT productivity is at least as likely due to deficiencies in our measurement and methodological tool kit as to mismanagement by developers and users of IT. One can only conclude, as Attewell and Rule (1984) did in an earlier survey, that we still have much o learn about how to measure the effects of computers on organizations. While particular emphasis is placed on economic approaches to both theory and empirics in this review, it is hoped that the process of addressing the productivity mystery will prove to be a useful springboard for other methodologies as well and for examining the broader issues involved. As a prelude to the literature survey, it is useful to define some of the terms used and to highlight some of the basic trends in the economics of IT. Definitions: * Information technology can be defined in various ways. Among the most common is the category Office, Computing and Accounting Machinery of the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) which consists primarily of computers. Some researchers use definitions that also include communications equipment, instruments, photocopiers and related equipment, and software and related services. * Labor productivity is calculated as the level of output divided by a given level of labor input. Multifactor productivity (sometimes more ambitiously called total factor productivity) is calculated as the level of output for a given level of several inputs, typically labor, capital and materials. In principle, multifactor productivity is a better guide to the efficiency of a firm or industry because it adjusts for shifts among inputs, such as an increase in capital intensity, but lack of data can make this consideration moot. Draft: 1/29/92 page 2 Information Technology and Productivity * In pr oductivity calculations, output is defined as the number of units produced times their unit value, proxied by their real price. Establishing the real price of a good or service requires the calculation of individual price deflators, often using hedonic methods, that eliminate the effects of inflation without ignoring quality changes. Trends: * The price of computing has dropped by half every 2-3 years1 (figure 3a and figure 3b). If progress in the rest of the economy had matched progress in the computer sector, a Cadillac would cost $4. 98, while ten minutes labor would buy a years worth of groceries. 2 * There have been increasing levels of business investment in information technology equipment. These investments now account for over 10% of new investment in capital equipment by American firms3 (figure 4). * Information processing continues to be the principal task undertaken by Americas work force. Over half the labor force is employed in information-handling activities. (figure 5). * Overall productivity growth has slowed significantly since the early 1970s and measured productivity growth has fallen especially sharply in the service sector, which consumes over 80% of IT (figure 2). * White collar productivity statistics have been essentially stagnant for 20 years. figure 6) 1 In the last 35 years, the quality-adjusted costs of computing have decreased by over 6000-fold relative to equipment prices outside the computer sector [Gordon, 1987]. This relationship has been dubbed Moores Law after John Moore who first documented the trend in microprocessors. It is widely projected to continue at least into the next century. 2 This comparison was inspired by the slightly exaggera ted claim in Forbes, [, 1980 #279], that If the auto industry had done what the computer industry has done, Rolls-Royce would cost $2. 50 and get 2,000,000 miles to the gallon. The $4. 98 Cadillac is based on a price of $30,890 for a 1991 Sedan de Ville divided by 6203, the relative deflator for computers. The grocery comparison is based on a wage of $10 an hour and $10,000 worth of groceries, each in actual 1991 dollars. 3 Some studies estimate that as much as 50% of recent equipment investment is in information technology [Kriebel, 1989 #417]. This higher figure seems to be partly due to a broader definition of IT. A discrepancy also arises when recent investments are expressed in 1982 dollars, when IT was relatively more expensive. This has the effect of boosting ITs real share over time faster than its nominal share grows. Draft: 1/29/92 page 3 Information Technology and Productivity These facts suggest two central questions, which comprise the productivity paradox: 1) Why are companies investing so heavily in information technology if it doesnt add to productivity? ) If information technology is contributing to productivity, why have we been unable to measure it? In seeking to answer these questions, this paper builds on a number of previous literature surveys. Much of the material in section III is adapted from an earlier paper with Bruce Bimber (Brynjolfsson Bimber, 1990) which also included an annotated bibliography of 104 related articles and a summary of six explanations for the productivity paradox from outside the economics literature. An earlier study by Crowston and Treacy (1986), identified 11 articles on the impact of IT on enterprise level performance by searching ten journals from 1975 to 1985. They conclude that there had been surprisingly little success in measuring the impact of IT and attribute this to the lack of clearly defined variables which in turn stems from an inadequacy of suitable reference disciplines and methodologies. One natural reference discipline is economics and an excellent review of recent research combining information systems and economics, by Bakos and Kemerer (1991), includes particularly relevant work in sections on macroeconomic impacts of information technology and information technology and organizational performance. Because statistical work is central to the majority of the approaches to assessing IT productivity, another very useful survey is Gurbaxani and Mendelsons (1989) paper on the use of data from secondary sources in MIS research. In addition to summarizing the work that has already been done, they make a convincing case that using pre-compiled data sets has significant advantages over starting de novo with original data, as has been the more common practice among MIS researchers. Finally, many of the papers that seek to directly Draft: 1/29/92 page 4 Information Technology and Productivity assess IT productivity begin with a literature survey. The reviews by Brooke (1991), Barua, Mukhopadhyay and Kriebel (1991), and Berndt and Morrison (1991b) were particularly useful. Although over 150 articles were considered in this review, it cannot claim to be comprehensive. Rather, it aims to clarify for the reader the principal issues surrounding IT and productivity, reflecting the results of a computerized literature search of 30 of the leading journals in both information systems and economics,4 and more importantly, discussions with many of the leading researchers in this area, who helped identify recent research that has not yet been published. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The next section summarizes the empirical research that has attempted to measure the productivity of information technology. Section III classifies the explanations for the paradox into four basic categories and assesses the components of each in turn. Section IV concludes with summaries of the key issues identified and some avenues for further research. Dimensions of the Paradox Productivity is the fundamental measure of a technologys contribution. With this in mind, CEOs and line managers have increasingly begun to question their huge investments in computers and related technologies (Loveman, 1988). While major success 4 The journals searched included American Economic Review, Bell (Rand) Journal of Economics, Brookings Papers on Economics and Accounting, Econometrica, Economic Development Review, Economica, Economics Journal, Economist (Netherlands), Information Economics Policy, International Economics Review, Journal of Business Finance, Communications of the ACM, Database, Datamation, Decision Sciences, Harvard Business Review, IEEE Spectrum, IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, IEEE Transactions on Software Engineering, Information Management, Interfaces, Journal of Systems Management, Management Science, MIS Quarterly, Operations Research, and Sloan Management Review. Articles were selected if they indicated an emphasis on computers, information systems, information technology, decision support systems, expert systems, or high technology combined with an emphasis on productivity. Draft: 1/29/92 page 5 Information Technology and Productivity stories exist, so do equally impressive failures (see, for example (Kemerer Sosa, 1990; Schneider, 1987)). The lack of good quantitative measures for the output and value created by information technology has made the MIS managers job of justifying investments particularly difficult. Academics have had similar problems assessing the contributions of this critical new technology, and this has been generally interpreted as a negative signal of its value. The disappointment in information technology has been chronicled in articles disclosing broad negative correlations with economy-wide productivity and information worker productivity. Econometric estimates have also indicated low IT capital productivity in a variety of manufacturing and service industries. The principal empirical research studies of IT and productivity are listed in table 1. Draft: 1/29/92 page 6 Information Technology and Productivity Table 1: Principal Empirical Studies of IT and Productivity Economy-wide Cross-sector or (Jonscher, 1983; Jonscher, 1988) (Baily Chakrabarti, 1988; Baily, 1986b; Baily Gordon, 1988) (Roach, 1987a; Roach, 1988; Roach, 1989b) (Brooke, 1991) (Osterman, 1986) (Grove, 1990) (Dos Santos, Peffers Mauer, 1991) Manufacturing (Berndt Morrison, 1991b) (Siegel Griliches, 1991) (Loveman, 1988) (Weill, 1988) (Dudley Lasserre, 1989) (Morrison Berndt, 1990) (Barua, Kriebel Mukhopadhyay, 1991) Services (Cron Sobol, 1983) (Strassman, 1985) (Baily, 1986a) (Roach, 1991; Roach, 1987b; Roach, 1989a) (Noyelle, 1990) (Brand Duke, 1982) (Pulley Braunstein, 1984) (Bender, 1986) (Bresnahan, 1986) (Franke, 1987) (Harris Katz, 1988; Harris Katz, 1989) (Parsons, Gotlieb Denny, 1990) (Weitzendorf Wigand, 1991) Economv-wide Productivity and Information Worker Productivitv The Issue One of the core issues for economists in the past decade has been the productivity slowdown that began in the early 1970s. There has been a drop in labor productivity growth from about 2. 5% per year between 1953-1968 to about 0. 7% per year from 1973- 1979. Multi-factor productivity growth, which takes into account changes in capital, declined from 1. 75% a year to 0. 32% over the same periods (Baily, 1986b). Even after accounting for factors such as the oil price shocks, changes in labor quality and potential measurement errors, most researchers still find that there is an unexplained residual drop in Correlations Models II . w w If i Draft: 1/29/92 page 7 i Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 8 productivity as compared with the first half of the post-war period. The sharp drop in productivity roughly coincided with the rapid increase in the use of information technology (figure 1). Although recent productivity growth has rebounded somewhat, especially in manufacturing, the overall negative correlation between economy-wide productivity and the advent of computers is at the core of many of the arguments that information technology has not helped US productivity or even that information technology investments have been counter-productive (Baily, 1986b). This link is made more explicit in research by Stephen Roach (1987a; 1988) focusing specifically on information workers, regardless of industry. While in the past, office work was not very capital intensive, recently the level of information technology capital per (white collar) information worker has begun approaching that of (blue collar) production capital per production worker. Concurrently, the ranks of information workers have ballooned and the ranks of production workers have shrunk. Roach cites statistics indicating that output per production worker grew by 16. 9% between the mid- 1970s and 1986, while output per information worker decreased by 6. 6%. He concludes: We have in essence isolated Americas productivity shortfall and shown it to be concentrated in that portion of the economy that is the largest employer of white-collar workers and the most heavily endowed with high-tech capital. Roachs analysis provides quantitative support for widespread reports of low office productivity. 5 A more sanguine explanation is put forth by Brooke (1991). Although he confirmed a broad-level correlation with declines in productivity, he hypothesized that this was due to increases in product variety which resulted in commensurate reductions in economies of scale. This hypothesis was supported by his finding of a positive correlation 5 For instance, Lester Thurow has noted that the American factory works, the American office doesnt, citing examples from the auto industry indicating that Japanese managers are able to get more output from blue collar workers (even in American plants) with up to 40% fewer managers. III Information Technology and Productivity between IT investment and the number of trademark applications. Because variety generally has positive value to consumers, but is ignored by conventional measures of productivity, this finding suggests a measurement problem, which is explored more fully in below in the section on mismeasurement. Comment Upon closer examination, the alarming correlation between IT and lower productivity at the level of the entire US economy is not compelling because so many other factors affect output and therefore productivity. Until recently, computers were not a major share of the economy. Consider the following order of magnitude estimates. Information technology capital stock is currently equal to about 10% of GNP, or total output. If, hypothetically, IT were being used efficiently and its marginal product were 20% (exceeding the return to most other capital investments), then current GNP would be directly increased about 2% (10% x 20%) because of the existence of our current stock of IT. However, information technology capital stock did not jump to its current level in the past year alone. Instead, the increase must be spread over about 30 years, suggesting an average contribution to aggregate GNP growth of 0. 06% in each year. 6 This would be very difficult to isolate because so many other factors affected GNP, especially in the relatively turbulent 1970s and early 1980s. Indeed, if the marginal product of IT capital were anywhere from -20% to +40%, it would still not have affected aggregate GNP growth by more than about 0. 1% per year and productivity growth by even less. 7 6 In his comment on Baily and Gordon (1988), David Romer notes that a similar argument applies to almost any capital investment. 7 In dollar terms, each white collar worker is endowed with about $10,000 in IT capital, which at a 20% ROI, would increase his or her total output about by about $2000 per year as compared with pre-computer levels of output. Compare to the $100,000 or so in salary and overhead that it costs to employ this worker and the expectations for a technological silver bullet seem rather ambitious. Draft: 1/29/92 page 9 Information Technology and Productivity This is not to say that computers may not have had significant effects in specific areas, like transaction processing, or on other characteristics of the economy, like employment shares, organizational structure or product variety. Rather it suggests that very large changes in capital stock are needed to measurably change total output under conventional assumptions about typical rates of return. However, the growth in information technology stock is still strong and the share of the total economy accounted for by computers is becoming quite substantial. Presumably, if computers are productive, we should begin to notice changes at the level of aggregate GNP in the near future. As for the apparent stagnation in white collar productivity, one should bear in mind that relative productivity cannot be directly inferred from the number of information workers per unit output. For instance, if a new delivery schedule optimizer allows a firm to substitute a clerk for two truckers, the increase in the number of white collar workers is evidence of an increase, not a decrease, in their relative productivity and in the firms productivity as well. Osterman (1986) suggests that this is why clerical employment often increases after the introduction of computers and Berndt and Morrison (199lb) confirm that information technology capital is, on average, a complement for white collar labor even as it leads to fewer blue collar workers. Unfortunately, more direct measures of office worker productivity are exceedingly difficult. Because of the lack of hard evidence, Panko (1984; 1991) has gone so far as to call the idea of stagnant office worker productivity a myth, although he cites no evidence to the contrary. Independent of its implications for productivity, growth in the white collar work force cannot be entirely blamed on information technology. Although over 38% of workers now use computers in their jobs8, the ranks of information workers began to 8 According to the US National Center for Education Statistics, 38. 3% of persons in the 1989 Current Population Survey used computers at work, including nearly 60% of those with four or more years of college. Interestingly, Kreuger [, 1991 #411] finds that workers using computers are paid an average wage premium of 8%, even after controlling for education, computer literacy and other factors. Draft: 1/29/92 page 10 Information Technology and Productivity surge well before the advent of computers (Porat, 1977). Jonscher (1988) even goes so far as to argue that causality goes the other way: the increased demand for information enabled economies of scale and learning in the computer industry, thereby reducing costs. These mitigating factors notwithstanding, the low measured productivity at the level of the whole economy and among white collar workers, especially in the face of huge increases in the accompanying capital stock, does call for closer scrutiny. A more direct case for weakness in information technologys contribution comes from the explicit evaluation of information technology capital productivity, typically by estimating the coefficients of a production function. This has been done in both manufacturing and service industries, and we review each in turn. The Productivity of Information Technology Capital in Manufacturing The Issues There have been at least seven studies of IT productivity in the manufacturing sector, summarized in table 2. A study by Gary Loveman (1988) provided some of the first econometric evidence of a potential problem when he examined data from 60 business units. 9 As is common in the productivity literature, he used ordinary least squares regression and assumed that production functions could be approximated by a Cobb-Douglas function. By taking the logarithm of all variables, he was able to estimate a linear relationship between changes in the log of output 0Â ° (q) and changes in the log of spending on key inputs, including 9 Namely, the Management Productivity of IT (MPIT) subset of the PIMS data set. 10 Where output was defined as (sales + net change in inventories)/ price index. Draft: 1/29/92 page 11 Information Technology and Productivity materials (m), purchased services (ps), labor (1), traditional capital (k), and information technology capital (c), while allowing for an exogenous time trend (), and an error term (? ): q = Blm + B2ps + 1331 + 4k + 135c + X + ? (1) Loveman estimated that the contribution of information technology capital to output (135) was approximately zero over the five year period studied in almost every subsample he examined. His findings were fairly robust to a number of variations on his basic formulation and suggest a paradox: while firms were demonstrating a voracious appetite for a technology experiencing radical improvements, measured productivity gains were insignificant. While Lovemans dependent variable was final output, Barua, Kriebel and Mukhopadhyay (1991) traced Lovemans results back a step by looking at ITs effect on intermediate variables such as capacity utilization, inventory turnover, quality, relative price and new product introduction. Using the same data set, they found that IT was positively related to three of these five intermediate measures of performance, although the magnitude of the effect was generally too small to measurably affect final output. Dudley and Lasserre (1989) also found econometric support for the hypothesis that better communication and information reduce the need for inventories, without explicitly relating this to bottom-line performance measures. Using a different data set, Weill (1988) was also able to disaggregate IT by use, and found that significant productivity could be attributed to transactional types of information technology (e. g. data processing), but was unable to identify gains associated with strategic systems (e. g. sales support) or informational investments (e. g. email infrastructure). Draft: 1/29/92 page 12 Information Technology and Productivity Morrison and Berndt have written two papers using a broader data set from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) that encompasses the whole U. S. manufacturing sector. The first (Morrison Berndt, 1990), which examined a series of highly parameterized models of production, found evidence that every dollar spent on IT delivered, on average, only about $0. 80 of value on the margin, indicating a general overinvestment in IT. Their second paper (Berndt Morrison, 1991b) took a less structured approach and examined broad correlations of IT with labor productivity and multifactor productivity, as well as other variables. This approach did not find a significant difference between the productivity of IT capital and other types of capital for a majority of the 20 industry categories examined. They did find that IT was correlated with significantly increased demand for skilled labor. Finally, Siegel and Griliches (1991) used industry and establishment data from a variety of sources to examine several possible biases in conventional productivity estimates. Among their findings was a positive simple correlation between an industrys level of investment in computers and its multifactor productivity growth in the 1980s. They did not examine more structural approaches, in part because of troubling concerns they raised regarding the reliability of the data and government measurement techniques. Draft: 1/29/92 page 13 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 14 Table 2: Studies of IT in Manufacturing Study Data source Findings Loveman, 1988) PIMS/MPIT IT investments added nothing to output (Weill, 1988) Valve manufacturers Contextual variables affect IT performance (Dudley Lasserre, IT and communication reduces inventories 1989) (Morrison Berndt, BEA IT marginal benefit is 80 cents per dollar 1990) invested (Barua, Kriebel PIMS/MPIT IT improved inte rmediate outputs, if not Mukhopadhyay, 1991) necessarily final output (Berndt Morrison, BEA, BLS IT not correlated with higher multi-factor 1991 b) productivity in most industries, more labor use (Siegel Griliches, Multiple govt sources IT using industries tend to be more 1991) productive; government data is unreliable Comment All authors make a point of emphasizing the limitations of their respective data sets. The MPIT data, which both Loveman and Barua, Kriebel and Mukhopadhyay use, can be particularly unreliable. As Loveman is careful to point out, his results are based on dollar denominated outputs and inputs, and therefore depend on price indices which may not accurately account for changes in quality or the competitive structure of the industry. The results of both of these studies may also be unrepresentative to the extent that the relatively short period covered by the MPIT data, 1978- 83, was unusually turbulent. The BEA data may be somewhat more dependable but are subject to subtle biases due to the unintuitive techniques used to aggregate and classify establishments. One of Siegel and Griliches principal conclusions was that after auditing the industry numbers, we found that a non-negligible number of sectors were not consistently defined over time. However, the generally reasonable estimates derived for the other, non-information technology factors of production in each of the studies indicate that there may indeed be something worrisome, or at least special, about information technology. Additional III Information Technology and Productivity econometric work would go far toward establishing whether these results are an artifact of the data or a genuine puzzle in need of more thorough analysis. The Productivity of Information Technology Capital in Services The Issues It has been widely reported that most of the productivity slowdown is concentrated in the service sector (1991; Roach, 1987b; Schneider, 1987). Before about 1970, service productivity growth was comparable to that in manufacturing, but since then the trends have diverged significantly. Meanwhile services have dramatically increased as a share of total employment and to a lesser extent, as a share of total output. Because services use over 80% information technology, this has been taken as indirect evidence of poor information technology productivity. The studies that have tried to assess IT productivity in the service sector are summarized in table 3. One of the first studies of ITs impact was by Cron and Sobol (1983), who looked at a sample of wholesalers. They found that on average, ITs impact was not significant, but that it seemed to be associated with both very high and very low performers. This finding has engendered the hypothesis that IT tends to reinforce existing management 11 According to government statistics, from 1953 to 1968, labor productivity growth in services averaged 2. 56%, vs. 2. 61% in manufacturing. For 1973 to 1979, the figures are 0. 68% vs. 1. 53%, respectively (Baily, 1986). However, a recent study (Gordon, 1989) suggests that measurement errors in US statistics systematically understate service productivity growth relative to manufacturing. More recently, computers definitely have caused some divergence in the statistics on manufacturing and service productivity, but for a very different reason. Because of the enormous quality improvements attributed to the computers, the nonelectrical machinery category (containing the computer producing industry) has shown tremendous growth. As a result, while overall manufacturing productivity growth has rebounded from about 1. 5% in the 1970s to 3. 5% in the 1980s, about two thirds of this increase is simply attributable to the greater production (as opposed to use) of computers (see comment by William Nordhaus on Baily Gordon, 1988 and section III. A of this paper) Draft: 1/29/92 page 15 Information Technology and Productivity approaches, helping well-organized firms succeed but only further confusing anagers who havent properly structured production in the first place. Strassman (1985; 1990) also reports disappointing evidence in several studies. In particular, he found that there was no correlation between IT and return on investment in a sample of 38 service sector firms: some top performers invest heavily in IT, while some do not. In his most recent book (1990), he concludes that there is no relation between spending for computers, profits and productivity. Roachs widely cited research on white collar productivity, discussed above, focused principally on ITs dismal performance in the service sector (1991; 1987a; 1987b; 1988; 1989a; 1989b). Roach argues that IT is an effectively used substitute for labor in most manufacturing industries, but has paradoxically been associated with bloating whitecollar employment in services, especially finance. He attributes this to relatively keener competitive pressures in manufacturing and foresees a period of belt-tightening and restructuring in services as they also become subject to international competition. There have been several studies of ITs impact on the performance of various types of financial services firms. A recent study by Parsons, Gottlieb and Denny (1990) estimated a production function for banking services in Canada and found that overall, the impact of IT on multifactor productivity was quite low between 1974 and 1987. They speculate that IT has positioned the industry for greater growth in the future. Similar conclusions are reached by Franke (1987), who found that IT was associated with a sharp drop in capital productivity and stagnation in labor productivity, but remained optimistic about the future potential of IT, citing the long time lags associated with previous technological transformations such as the conversion to steam power. On the other Draft: 1/29/92 page 16 Information Technology and Productivity hand, Brand (1982), using BLS data and techniques, found that moderate productivity growth had already occurred in banking. Harris and Katz (1988; 1989) and Bender (1986) looked at data on the insurance industry from the Life Office Management Association Information Processing Database. They found a positive relationship between IT expense ratios and various performance ratios although at times the relationship was quite weak. Several case studies of ITs impact on performance have also been done, including one by Weitzendorf Wigand (1991) which developed a model of information use in two service corporations, and a study of an information services firm by Pulley and Braunstein (1984), which found an association with increased economies of scope. Table 3: Studies of IT in Services Study Data source Findings (Brand Duke, 1982) BLS Productivity growth of 1. 3%/yr in banking (Cron Sobol, 1983) 138 medical supply Bimodal distribution among high IT wholesalers investors: either very good or very bad (Pulley Braunstein, Monthly data from Significant economies of scope 1984) information service firm (Clarke, 1985) Case study Major business process redesign needed to reap benefits in investment firm Strassman, 1985; Computerworld survey No correlation between various IT ratios Strassman, 1990)] of 38 companies and performance measures (Bender, 1986) LOMA insurance data on Weak relationship between IT and variou s 132 firms performance ratios (Bresnahan, 1986) Financial services firms Large gains in imputed consumer welfare (Franke, 1987) Finance industry data (Roach, 1991; Roach, Principally BLS, BEA Vast increase in IT capital per information 1987b; Roach, 1989a) worker while measured output decreased (Harris Katz, 1988; LOMA insurance data Weak positive relationship between IT and Harris Katz, 1989) for 40 various performance ratios Noyelle, 1990) US and French industry Severe measurement problems in services (Parsons, Gotlieb Internal operating data IT coefficient in translog production Denny, 1990) from 2 large banks function small and often negative (Weitzendorf Interviews at 2 Interactive model of information use Wigand, 1991) companies Draft: 1/29/92 page 17 Information Technology and Productivity Comment Measurement problems are even more acute in services than in manufacturing. In part, this arises because many service transactions are idiosyncratic, and therefore not subject to statistical aggregation. Unfortunately, even when abundant data exist, classifications sometimes seem arbitrary. For instance, in accordance with a fairly standard approach, Parsons, Gottlieb and Denny (1990) treated time deposits as inputs into the banking production function and demand deposits as outputs. The logic for such decisions is often difficult to fathom and subtle changes in deposit patterns or classification standards can have disproportionate impacts. The importance of variables other than IT also becomes particularly apparent in some of the service sector studies. Cron and Sobols finding of a bimodal distribution suggests that some variable was left out of the equation. Furthermore, researchers and consultants have increasingly emphasized the theme of re-engineering work when introducing major IT investments (Davenport Short, 1990; Hammer, 1990). A frequently cited example is the success of the Batterymarch services firm, as documented by Clarke (1985). Batterymarch used information technology to radically restructure the investment management process, rather than simply overlaying IT on existing processes. In sum, while a number of the dimensions of the information technology productivity paradox have been overstated, the question remains as to whether information technology is having the positive impact expected. In particular, better measures of information worker productivity are needed, as are explanations for why information technology capital hasnt clearly improved firm-level productivity in manufacturing and services. We now examine four basic approaches taken to answer these questions. Draft: 1/29/92 page 18 Information Technology and Productivity Leading Explanations for the Paradox Although it is too early to conclude that ITs productivity contribution has been subpar, a paradox remains in our inability to unequivocally document any contribution after so much effort. The various explanations that have been proposed can be grouped into four categories: 1) Mismeasurement of outputs and inputs, 2) Lags due to learning and adjustment, 3) Redistribution and dissipation of profits, 4) Mismanagement of information and technology. The first two explanations point to shortcomings in research, not practice, as the root of the productivity paradox. It is possible that the benefits of IT investment are quite large, but that a proper index of its true impact has yet to be analyzed. Traditional measures of the relationship between inputs and outputs fail to account for non-traditional sources of value. Second, if significant lags between cost and benefit may exist, then short-term results look poor but ultimately the pay-off will be proportionately larger. This would be the case if extensive learning, by both individuals and organizations, were needed to fully exploit IT, as it is for most radically new technologies. A more pessimistic view is embodied in the other two explanations. They propose that there really are no major benefits, now or in the future, and seek to explain why managers would systematically continue to invest in information technology. The redistribution argument suggests that those investing in the technology benefit privately but at the expense of others, so no net benefits show up at the aggregate level. The final type of explanation examined is that we have systematically mismanaged information Draft: 1/29/92 page 19 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 20 technology: there is something in its nature that leads firms or industries to invest in it when they shouldnt, to misallocate it, or to use it to create slack instead of productivity. Each of these four sets of hypotheses is assessed in turn in this section. Measurement Errors The Issues The easiest explanation for the low measured productivity of information technology is simply that were not properly measuring output. Denison (1989) makes a wide-ranging case that productivity and output statistics can be very unreliable. Most economists would agree with the evidence presented by Gordon and Baily (1989), and Noyelle (1990) that the problems are particularly bad in service industries, which happen to own the majority of information technology capital. It is important to note that measurement errors need not necessarily bias IT productivity if they exist in comparable magnitudes both before and after IT investments. However, the sorts of benefits ascribed by managers to information technology increased quality, variety, customer service, speed and responsiveness are precisely the aspects of output measurement that are poorly accounted for in productivity statistics as well as in most firms accounting numbers. This can lead to systematic underestimates of IT productivity. The measurement problems are particularly acute for IT use in the service sector and among white collar workers. Since the null hypothesis that no improvement occurred wins by default when no measured improvement is found, it probably is not coincidental that service sector and information worker productivity is considered more of a problem than manufacturing and blue collar productivity, where measures are better. III Information Technology and Productivity a. Output Mismeasurement As discussed in the introduction, when comparing two output levels, it is important to deflate the prices so they are in comparable real dollars. Accurate price adjustment should remove not only the effects of inflation but also adjust for any quality changes. Much of the measurement problem arises from the difficulty of developing accurate, quality-adjusted price deflators. Additional problems arise when new products or features are introduced, not only because they have no predecessors for direct comparison, but also because variety itself has value, and that can be nearly impossible to measure. The positive impact of information technology on variety and the negative impact of variety on measured productivity has been econometrically and theoretically supported by Brooke (1991). He argues that lower costs of information processing have enabled companies to handle more products and more variations of existing products. However, the increased scope has been purchased at the cost of reduced economies of scale and has therefore resulted in higher unit costs of output. For example, if a clothing manufacturer chooses to produce more colors and sizes of shirts, which may have value to consumers, existing productivity measures rarely account for such value and will typically show higher productivity in a firm that produces a single color and size. 12 Higher prices in industries with increasing product diversity is likely to be attributed to inflation, despite the real increase in value provided to consumers. In services, the problem of unmeasured improvements can be even worse than in manufacturing. For instance, the convenience afforded by twenty-four hour ATMs is frequently cited as an unmeasured quality improvement (Banker Kauffman, 1988). 12The same phenomenon suggests that much of the initial decline in productivity experienced by centrally-planned economies when they liberalize is spurious. Draft: 1/29/92 page 21 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 22 How much value has this contributed to banking customers? Government statistics implicitly assume it is all captured in the number of transactions, or worse, that output is a constant multiple of labor input! (Mark, 1982) In a case study of the finance, insurance and real estate sector, where computer usage and the numbers of information workers are particularly high, Baily and Gordon (Baily Gordon, 1988) identified a number of practices by the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) which tend to understate productivity growth. Their revisions add 2. 3% per year to productivity between 1973 and 1987 in this sector. 13 b. Information Technology Stock Mismeasurement A related measurement issue is how to measure information technology stock itself. For any given amount of output, if the level of IT stock used is overestimated, then its unit productivity will appear to be less than it really is. Denison (1989) argues that the rapid decreases in the real costs of computer power are largely a function of general advances in knowledge and as a result, the government overstates the decline in the computer price deflator by attributing these advances to the producing industry. If this is true, the real quantity of computers purchased recently is not as great as statistics show, while the real quantity purchased 20 years ago is higher. The net result is that much of the productivity improvement that the government attributes to the computer-producing industry, should be allocated to computer-using industries. Effectively, computer users have been overcharged for their recent computer investments in the government productivity calculations. c. Input Mismeasurement 13 They also add 1. 1% to productivity growth before 1973. III Information Technology and Productivity A third issue is the measurement of other inputs. If the quality of work life is improved by computer usage (less repetitive retyping, tedious tabulation and messy mimeos), then theory suggests that proportionately lower wages can be paid. Thus the slow growth in clerical wages may be an artifact of unmeasured improvements in work life that are not accounted for in government statistics. Baily and Gordon (1988) conjecture that this may also be adding to the underestimation of productivity. To the extent that complementary inputs, such as software, or training, are required to make investments in information technology worthwhile, labor input may also be overestimated. Although spending on software and training yields benefits for several years, it is generally expensed in the same year that computers are purchased, artificially raising the short-term costs associated with computerization. In an era of annually rising investments, the subsequent benefits would be masked by the subsequent expensing of the next, larger, round of complementary inputs. On the other hand, IT purchases may also create long-term liabilities in software and hardware maintenance that are not fully accounted for, leading to an underestimate of ITs impact on costs. d. Methodological Concerns In addition to data problems, the methodology used to assess IT impacts can also significantly affect the results. Alpar and Kim (1990) applied two approaches to the same data set. One approach was based on key ratios and the other used a cost function derived from microeconomic theory. 4 They found that the key ratios approach, which had been 14 An example of the key ratios approach is examining the correlation between the ratio of information processing expenses to total expenses and the ratio of total operating expenses to premium income, as Bender [, 1986 #295] did. An example of the cost function approac h is to use duality theory to derive a cost function from a production function, such as the Cobb-Douglas function described above that was used by Loveman [, 1988 #58]. The exact function used by Alpar and Kim was the translog cost function, which is more general, but which requires the estimation of a large number of parameters. Draft: 1/29/92 page 23 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 24 previously used by Bender (1986) and Cron and Sobol (1983), among others, could be particularly misleading. In an effort to model IT effects more rigorously, several papers have called for the use of approaches derived from microeconomics. Cooper and Mukhopadhyay (1990) advocate a production function approach while frontier methodologies such as data envelopment analysis (DEA) have been proposed by Chismar and Kriebel (1985) and Stabell (1982). A very different approach has been applied in an article by Tim Bresnahan (1986). Recognizing the inherent difficulties in measurement in the financial services sector, Bresnahan made no attempt to directly measure output. Instead, he inferred it from the level of spending on mainframes under the assumption that the unregulated parts of the financial services sector were competitive and were therefore acting as agents for consumers. He found that welfare gains were five times greater than expenditures through 1973. Bresnahans findings serve to underscore the size of the gap between the benefits perceived by the consumers of IT and those measured by researchers using conventional techniques. Comments Output measurement is undoubtedly problematic. Rapid innovation has made information technology-intensive industries particularly susceptible to the problems associated with measuring quality changes and valuing new products. The way productivity statistics are currently kept can lead to bizarre anomalies: to the extent that ATMs lead to fewer checks being written, they can actually lower productivity statistics. Increased variety, improved timeliness of delivery and personalized customer service are additional benefits that are poorly represented in productivity statistics. These are all qualities that are particularly likely to be enhanced by information technology. Because III Information Technology and Productivity information is intangible, increases in the implicit information content of products and services are likely to be under-measured compared to increases in materials content. Nonetheless, some analysts are skeptical that measurement problems can explain much of the slowdown. They point out that by many measures, service quality has gone down, not up. 15 Furthermore, they question the value of variety when it takes the form of six dozen brands of breakfast cereal. Indeed, models from industrial organization theory suggest that while more variety will result from the flexible manufacturing and lower search costs enabled by IT, the new equilibrium can exhibit excess variety making consumers worse off (Tirole, 1988). Denison is in the minority in his view that the government is overestimating the improvements in computing power per dollar. A study by Gordon (1987) found that, if anything, computer prices are declining slightly faster than government statistics show. More recently, a study by Triplett (1989) considered Denisons criticisms but in the end supported the BEA methods. 16 Ultimately, a closer look at productivity statistics reminds researchers that the poor showing of information technology may not rest on an entirely solid foundation simply because the statistics are not as reliable as we would like. Lags The Issues 5 Nordhaus in a comment on Baily and Gordon (1988) recalls the doctors house call, custom tailoring, and windshield wipin g at gas stations, among other relics. 16 Most economists appear to be less concerned than Denison about this bias in the BEA statistics. For instance, a consensus of economists at the June, 1990 NBER conference on productivity concurred with Tripletts conclusions. Draft: 1/29/92 page 25 Information Technology and Productivity A second explanation for the paradox is that the benefits from information technology can take several years to show up on the bottom line. a. Evidence of Lags The idea that new technologies may not have an immediate impact is a common one in business. For instance, a survey of executives suggested that many expected it to take at much as five years for information technology investments to pay-off (Nolan/Norton, 1988). This accords with a recent econometric study by Brynjolfsson et al. (1991a) which found lags of two to four years before the strongest organizational impacts of information technology were felt. Loveman (1988) also found slightly higher, albeit still very low, productivity when small lags were introduced. In general, while the benefits from investment in infrastructure can be large, they are indirect and often not immediate. b. Theoretical Basis for Lags The existence of lags has some basis in theory. Because of its unusual complexity and novelty, firms and individual users of information technology may require some experience before becoming proficient (Curley Pyburn, 1982). According to dynamic models of learning-by-using, the optimal investment strategy sets short term marginal costs greater than short-term marginal benefits. This allows the firm to ride the learning curve and reap benefits analogous to economies of scale (Scherer, 1980). If only short-term costs and benefits are measured, then it might appear that the investment was inefficient. Viewed in this framework, there is nothing irrational about the experimentation phase firms are said to experience in which rigorous cost/benefit analysis is not undertaken (Nolan/Norton, 1988). Because future information technology investments tend to be large Draft: 1/29/92 page 26 Information Technology and Productivity relative to current investments, the learning effect could potentially be quite substantial. A similar pattern of costs and benefits is predicted by an emerging literature that treats investments in information technology as options, with short term costs, but with the potential for long-term benefits (Kambil, Henderson Mohsenzadeh, 1991). Comments One way to address the measurement problem associated with complementary inputs (see section III. A. 1 . c) is to introduce appropriate lags in the estimation procedure. For instance, the purchase of a mainframe computer must generally precede the development of mainframe database software. Software, in turn, usually precedes data acquisition. Good decisions may depend on years of acquired data and may not instantaneously lead to profits. 17 Optimally, a manager must take into account these longterm benefits when purchasing a computer and so must the researcher seeking to verify the benefits of computerization. If managers are rationally accounting for lags, this explanation for low information technology productivity growth is particularly optimistic. In the future, not only should we reap the then-current benefits of the technology, but also enough additional benefits to make up for the extra costs we are currently incurring. However, the credibility of this explanation is somewhat undermined by the fact that American managers have not been noted for their ability to postpone benefits to the future. On the contrary, the risk and uncertainty associated with new technologies can make risk-averse managers require higher, not lower, rates of return before they will invest. Increased familiarity, ease-of-use 17 It has been observation that firms that spend proportionately more money on software appear to be more profitable (Computer Economics Report, 1988) If firms go through a hardware buying phase followed by an applications phase, then this may have more to due with firms being in different stages of a multi-year process than with different technology strategies. Draft: 1/29/92 page 27 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 28 and end-user computing may lead to reduced lags between the costs and benefits of computerization in the future. Redistribution The Issues A third possible explanation is that information technology may be beneficial to individual firms, but unproductive from the standpoint of the industry as a whole or the economy as a whole: IT rearranges the shares of the pie without making it any bigger. a. The Private Value of Information Can Exceed its Social Value There are several arguments for why redistribution may be more of a factor with IT investments than for other investments. For instance, information technology may be used disproportionately for market research and marketing, activities which can be very beneficial to the firm while adding nothing to total output (Baily Chakrabarti, 1988; Lasserre, 1988). Furthermore, economists have recognized for some time that, compared to other goods, information is particularly vulnerable to rent dissipation, in which one firms gain comes entirely at the expense of others, instead of by creating new wealth. As Hirshleifer (1971) pointed out, advance knowledge of demand, supply, weather or other conditions that affect asset prices can be very profitable privately even without increasing total output. This will lead to excessive incentives for information gathering. In a similar spirit, races to be the first to apply an innovation can also lead to rent dissipation (Fudenberg Tirole, 1985). The rapid-fire pace of innovation in the information technology industry might also encourage this form of wasteful investment. III Information Technology and Productivity b. Models of Redistribution Baily and Chakrabarti (1988) run a simulation under the assumption that a major share of the private benefits of information technology result from redistribution. The results are broadly consistent with the stylized facts of increased amounts of information technology and workers without increases in total productivity. 2. Comments Unlike the other possible explanations, the redistribution hypothesis would not explain any shortfall in IT productivity at the firm-level: firms with inadequate IT budgets would lose market share and profits to high IT spenders. In this way, an analogy could be made to models of the costs and benefits of advertising. It is interesting to note that most of the reasons for investing in information technology given by the articles in the business press involve taking profits from competitors rather than lowering costs. 18 Mismanagement The Issues A fourth possibility is that, on the whole, information technology really is not productive at the firm level. The investments are made nevertheless because the decision- 18 Porter and Millar, 1985, is not atypical. They emphasize competitive advantage gained by changes in industry structure, product and service differentiation and spawning of new businesses while devoting about 5% of their space to cost savings enabled by IT. Others ignore cost reductions entirely. Draft: 1/29/92 page 29 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 30 makers arent acting in the interests of the firm. Instead, they are a) increasing their slack, b) signalling their prowess or c) simply using outdated criteria for decision-making. a. Increased scope for managerial slack Many of the difficulties that researchers have in quantifying the benefits of information technology would also affect managers (Baily, 1986a; Gremillion Pyburn, 1985). As a result, they may have difficulty in bringing the benefits to the bottom line if output targets, work organization and incentives are not appropriately adjusted (McKersie Walton, 1988). The result is that information technology might increase organizational slack instead of output or profits. This is consistent with arguments by Roach (1989a) that manufacturing has made better use of information technology than has the service sector because manufacturing faces greater global competition, and thus tolerates less slack. b. Information consumption as a signal Feldman and March (1981) also point out that good decisions are generally correlated with significant consumption of information. If the amount of information requested is more easily observable than the quality of decisions, a signalling model will show that too much information will be consumed. c. Use of outdated management heuristics A related argument derives from evolutionary models (Nelson, 1981). The difficulties in measuring the benefits of information and information technology discussed above may also lead to the use of heuristics, rather than strict cost/benefit accounting to set III Information Technology and Productivity levels of information technology investments. 9 Our current institutions, heuristics and management principles evolved largely in a world with little information technology. The radical changes enabled by information technology may make these institutions outdated (see e. g. (Clarke, 1985; Franke, 1987)). For instance, a valuable heuristic in 1960 might have been get all readily available information before making a decision. The same heuristic today could lead to information overload and chaos (Thurow, 1987). Indeed, Ayres (1989) argues that the rapid speed-up enabled by information technology creates unanticipated bottlenecks at each human in the information processing chain. More money spent on information technology wont help until these bottlenecks are addressed. Indeed, researchers have found that a successful IT implementation process must not simply overlay new technology on old processes (Davenport Short, 1990). At a broader level, several researchers suggest that our currently low productivity levels are symptomatic of an economy in transition, in this case to the information era (David, 1989; Franke, 1987; Gay Roach, 1986). For instance, David makes an analogy to the electrification of factories at the turn of the century. Major productivity gains did not occur for twenty years, when new factories were designed and built to take advantage of electricitys flexibility which enabled machines to be located based on work-flow efficiency, instead of proximity to waterwheels, steam-engines and power-transmitting shafts and rods. Comments While the idea of firms consistently making inefficient investments in IT is anathema to the neoclassical view of the firm as a profit-maximizer, it can be explained 19 Indeed, a recent review of the techniques used by major companies to justify information technology investments [Yamamoto, 1991] revealed surprisingly little formal analysis. See Clemons [, 1991 #284] for an assessment of the IT justification process. Draft: 1/29/92 page 31 Draft: 1/29/92 Information Technology and Productivity page 32 formally by models such as agency theory, employment signalling models and evolutionary economics, which treat the firm as a more complex entity. The fact that firms continue to invest large sums in the technology suggests that the individuals within the firm that make investment decisions are getting some benefit or at least believe they are getting some benefit from IT. For instance, a model of how IT enables managerial slack can be developed using agency theory. The standard result in this literature is that when managers (agent) incentives are not aligned with shareholder (principal) interests, suboptimal investment decisions and effort can result. One little noted feature of most agency models is that the incentives for agents to acquire additional information generally exceed the social benefits. This is because agents can use the information to earn rents and to short-circuit the incentive scheme (Brynjolfsson, 1990a). Thus, information technology investments may be very attractive to managers even when they do little to boost productivity. To the extent that competition reduces the scope for managerial slack, the problem is alleviated. In general, however, we do not yet have comprehensive models of the internal organization of the firm and researchers, at least in economics, are mostly silent on the sorts of inefficiency discussed in this section. Conclusion Summary Research on information technology

Wednesday, November 6, 2019

Free Essays on Ethics In Decision Making

Ethics in Decision Making The decision making processes that people go through in their lives can have many different influences. One of the more important influences in the decision making process is the ethics involved in a decision. This begs the question, â€Å"What are ethics?† One definition of ethics could be a structured set of guidelines for personal and professional behavior (Houghton Mifflin Company, 2000). Another definition could be the study of the moral choices people make, and what drives these choices (Houghton Mifflin Company). Regardless, not all decisions carry a significant ethical weight. It is important to recognize the decisions that do have ethical questions attached to them and to weigh the decision against an ethical standard. Ethics can have gray areas and vary from one culture to culture, or even from one person to the next. One person may decide it is ethical to sell a car â€Å"as is†, knowing the car needs expensive servicing or repairs. This person may suppose that the buyer should read into the â€Å"as is† tag and understand the inherent risks associated. This ethical standard could shock someone else who might think it the worst sort of deception. The key is to reflect on the values of the society in which you live, and the personal moral code that one lives by. In a society such as mainstream America, the above sale would be legal and even ethical in most jurisdictions. Ethical standards are particularly applicable to business and professions, and as such are largely constructions of laws. Despite the legality of the aforementioned car sale, such an act would likely be viewed unfavorably by the majority of people in American society. As such, any person who chose to try and make a living selling cars must understand that while the sale was legal, society will not tolerate this and act decisively. People would eventually choose not to buy cars from that person. They would tell their fri... Free Essays on Ethics In Decision Making Free Essays on Ethics In Decision Making Ethics in Decision Making The decision making processes that people go through in their lives can have many different influences. One of the more important influences in the decision making process is the ethics involved in a decision. This begs the question, â€Å"What are ethics?† One definition of ethics could be a structured set of guidelines for personal and professional behavior (Houghton Mifflin Company, 2000). Another definition could be the study of the moral choices people make, and what drives these choices (Houghton Mifflin Company). Regardless, not all decisions carry a significant ethical weight. It is important to recognize the decisions that do have ethical questions attached to them and to weigh the decision against an ethical standard. Ethics can have gray areas and vary from one culture to culture, or even from one person to the next. One person may decide it is ethical to sell a car â€Å"as is†, knowing the car needs expensive servicing or repairs. This person may suppose that the buyer should read into the â€Å"as is† tag and understand the inherent risks associated. This ethical standard could shock someone else who might think it the worst sort of deception. The key is to reflect on the values of the society in which you live, and the personal moral code that one lives by. In a society such as mainstream America, the above sale would be legal and even ethical in most jurisdictions. Ethical standards are particularly applicable to business and professions, and as such are largely constructions of laws. Despite the legality of the aforementioned car sale, such an act would likely be viewed unfavorably by the majority of people in American society. As such, any person who chose to try and make a living selling cars must understand that while the sale was legal, society will not tolerate this and act decisively. People would eventually choose not to buy cars from that person. They would tell their fri...

Monday, November 4, 2019

Business research project Essay Example | Topics and Well Written Essays - 2000 words

Business research project - Essay Example According to Bruce (2001) until now the demand to sensitize the business teachers who are trained to enhance international field experience has been driven further and acknowledged widely. This is due to the movement of world cultures and global contacts that are increasing through international experience. In this respect, the new rule is that many businesses are increasing their diversity and enrolling their employees with challenging and unique needs to teachers that are recruited internationally. This has made managers and business employees to be agents of responsibility for global and cultural responsibility within the business. In business management, international field experience is a vital aspect to the educational professionals who prepare for natural resource and business management industries. It gives out experience which reinforces the instruction of the business management. It also gives out a chance to business students to engage and observe the application of the kn owledge that has been acquired. This means that international field experience helps employees to achieve valuable insights towards the operation and organization of agencies and businesses in different industrial sectors. In this regard, field experience that is properly supervised and pursued with enthusiasm could be of significant meaning towards business management. However, there is hardly any research that has been done concerning the relevance of international field experience on business management. For this reason, this paper proposes a study to investigate the impacts of international field experience on business management. In this study, we will hypothesise that international field experience has increased positive impacts on business management. Purpose of international field experience. Field experience is a factor which is of great importance in business management. Its main purpose has always been to give managers a business of combining the theoretical studies with an application of practical knowledge in the actual environment of work. In the business students’ academic program, field experience plays a crucial role as it gives students a room for application of the knowledge gained while in the classroom. Field work also gives students a chance to continue learning under a professional supervisor during the field work. Additionally, student interns should always undertake their study abroad responsibilities with professional and quality dedication. Student interns are also expected to be assets to the agency of placement and that they need to establish an enormous contribution due to their experience in the work. The objective of the research. This is a research work that is set out to among other things achieve one key objective. Thus, the overarching objective was to find out the impacts of international field experience on business management. The topic to be examined would be the impacts of field experience on business management. Research Questions There are three essential questions considered in this study. These questions can support the research in its objective of achieving the possible answer to the thesis. What does International field experience entail? What are the effects of such international fie